There has been tons of attention on
income (and wealth) inequality in recent years—much of it driven by a nasty
combination of ignorance and envy. For example, folks often conflate income
inequality at a point in time with a lack of economic mobility over time. One
can easily have income inequality without any trouble in the realm of economic
opportunity—as people move between income classes, up and down the economic
ladder.
I've written a lot on the topic—in
an academic journal (here),
in a policy journal (here
and here),
a long list/review of commentary on Piketty, and through op-eds and blog posts (here,
here,
here,
here,
here,
here,
and here). Adding
to that pile, I'll offer a brief overview of Walter Scheidel's The Great Leveler.
In one way, the book is not all that
relevant, because one would rarely if ever advocate his historically-based
"solutions"—an array of disasters such as war—to the supposed and
real concerns with income inequality. But his book does help to put those
concerns in a more appropriate place—i.e., limited in importance and
contextualized with many other variables.
In this, I'm reminded of a Jim Rome line—that diarrhea is “the great
equalizer". It doesn't matter whether you're
rich or poor, the big D will bring you to your knees. Along the same lines,
Ignazio Silone observes that "An earthquake achieves what the law promises
but does not in practice maintain—the equality of all men." Great: we’re
mostly equal in terms of diarrhea and earthquakes! (If you want a much more
positive example, think about orgasms.)
By way of introduction, Scheidel starts
with the important issues outside the scope of his project. First, he notes what
the book does not cover: many of the standard reasons why incomes differ—from
education and work ethic to luck and discrimination (9-11). Second, he
discusses the most popular statistics—as proxies for the state of the world
they try to measure (11-18). It follows that looking at less-developed
countries or going back in time is an increasingly dubious exercise. But he
thinks the effort is still somewhat valuable. Third, he talks about the
connections between innovation and inequality—and wonders whether inequality is
all that important compared to poverty (18-22).
Part 1 of the book is a brief
history of income inequality, ranging from “the great apes” to Europe after World
War II. He notes the inequality of power in ape hierarchies (25-26). And he
notes Europe's high and generally growing inequality—except for its experience
with the fall of the Roman Empire, a plethora of plagues, and the Great
Depression.
The references to Europe's periodic
"improvements" in income inequality allow Scheidel to set the table
for the rest of the book and his focus on "the four horsemen" (5-9): War,
Revolution, State Collapse, and Plagues. He surveys history widely for
examples, as he draws out the implications for economies in general and
economic inequality in particular.
Scheidel notes that the accumulation
of capital and wealth proceeds with far greater ease during peaceful times—for
example, the 19th century West. (He cites Piketty's work
here [165], which is helpful on the role of capital formation in understanding
income inequality.) In contrast, wars (particularly civil wars) are damaging or
even devastating to economies, but "helpful" in promoting economic
equality.
Revolutions and the State Collapse
are cousins of War—and so, the impact is about the same. The case for Plagues
is less intuitive, since one might imagine that the wealthy would survive them
more effectively or that random deaths would leave overall inequality mostly
unchanged. But again, it's the general impact of plagues on overall economic health
that causes inequality to fall.
Even for those who are greatly concerned
about income inequality, the four horsemen are not an appropriate means to the
desired ends. (For one thing, the events are largely exogenous, rather than
something to be pursued!) In this sense, Scheidel's work is interesting and
provocative but more tongue-in-cheek than directly applicable.
So, in the final section, Scheidel
turns to more likely candidates—cousins of the horsemen that might yield enough
benefits to be worth the costs. He closes with three chapters on lessons
from the past and hopes for the future. But these are relatively speculative,
so I'm going to focus on his more concrete proposals.
In Chapter 12, he discusses the
theory and practice of modest "negative" efforts: "land
reform", debt relief, and economic crises. It seems like a stretch to
imagine economic crisis as palatable. But land reform and debt relief have been
proposed and tried—with far less success than was promised on paper.
In Chapter 13, Scheidel covers a
positive angle with improved education. This is more promising, especially
since we do such a poor job with K-12 now, despite spending an inordinate
amount of money. It’s easy to imagine how more competition and more private
sector involvement could allow us to make significant improvements with the
same spending or less.
Scheidel doesn't discuss family
structure/stability, but this would obvious help with education, as well as a
myriad of other social concerns. Unfortunately, cultural mores and economic
policies act to discourage strong family structure. Hopefully, the cycle will
turn again—as it has in the past. (This is the subject of a forthcoming paper
for me.)
Scheidel’s book is interesting
history. But its most useful contribution to politics and public policy is
putting income inequality in its place. There are far worse things in life than
income inequality.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
Subscribe to Post Comments [Atom]
<< Home